Defining Globalization Through Cities
I acknowledge for this section the limited purpose of describing globalization in relation to the role of cities as interregional connectors, particularly in light of a network conception of the city in topological space. With this frame of reference in mind, globalization simply constitutes one of a multiplicity of descriptions of long distance, multidirectional network connections between city regions existing over the course of human history. I will proceed from the position, mirroring those of Pred (1977), Bourne (1975) and, more recently, Taylor (2004), that such connections between city regions are continuously produced and reproduced over time.
To isolate a particular impression on the importance of interregional commerce to the development of cities, Jacobs (1970: 35; 1984: 135-155) insists on the impossibility of urban economic development in the absence of commercial exchange processes between cities, resulting in the articulation, development, transformation, collapse, and reproduction of interregional economic systems anchored by cities. The unique forms, in which such interregional city systems become manifest, demonstrate novelty in relation to the scale of the exchange networks developed. That is to say, trade networks among Mediterranean cities in the Twelfth century manifest a geographically different form and scale of distances from contemporary supply chains for computer hardware integrating cities at opposite corners of Pacific Rim.
The unifying characteristic of both such interregional systems of exchange remains the centrality of connecting cities as a condition of their existence. Sources of differentiation can be linked explicitly to characteristics of the networks articulated in different interregional systems linking particular city regions at particular moments in time. Especially, the types of transmission processes involved in distinct interregional networks yields an important source of difference. The extent to which technologies permit, over time, more radical space-time compression enables more pronounced extensions of networks through Cartesian space, making interregional networks relatively more global in nature. For example, information transmissions in the Twelfth century, involving particular methods and tools for written codification and transmission over relatively long distances between parties sharing capacities for translation (e.g. common written languages or easily translatable concepts in multiple written lingual structures), reflect particular constraints on the geographic extension of information transmission less apparent at the present time. By contrast, contemporary methods of wireless information communication enhance the speed of point-to-point information transmission processes, facilitating significance extensions in the distances between connected stationary information producing and/or collecting/disseminating nodes.
Continuing to emphasize the importance of integrating network theory into this understanding of globalization through cities, extensions of the length of networks never imply saturation of Cartesian space. Globalization, as the extension of interregional networks over longer and longer distances, never implies that transmissions from networked processes occupy broad, continuous fields in Cartesian space or, even, the pathways between individual nodes. To interject a Jacobsean image of interregional commerce anchored on cities, Twelfth century commodities flowed between Constantinople and Venice, but not to all points in between unless the transmission process, per se, has failed (e.g. interdiction of maritime transportation through piracy). Today, information travels from Seattle to Bangkok, but not to the Northwestern Pacific coastal or Thai countrysides or to all other intervening points not otherwise connected to the media by which information is transmitted. Wireless communications media do not perfectly or evenly saturate the global landscape with possibilities for connectivity, even with the appropriate accessing technologies – dead zones exist where no wireless communications media can reach. In short, if I analyze globalization through the frame of reference of networks, then the effects of transmissions generated by processes associated with globalization cannot be theorized as universal, in the sense that they diffuse to touch all points in Cartesian space. Rather, globalization describes the manifestation of effects, transmitted over long distances across diverse pathways, at discrete, identifiable nodes. The imagery of geographically uneven development conveyed by this network theory of globalization underscores the relative importance of cities as spaces through which long distance transmissions emanate and from which information, other use values, and people become unevenly dispersed across city regions.
Accepting these insights as a point of departure for an understanding of globalization consistent with Jacobs’ theorization of interregional city systems, this project seeks to move further to argue that interregional network connections are never simply commercial or, more generally, economic in nature. Rather, the sort of networked processes that connect cities to form interregional city systems of the kind envisioned by Jacobs include cultural and political processes as well. For example, movements of human beings, resulting in new diasporic settlement patterns for particular ethnic groups, may extend the geographic range for diverse collective cultural practices defining the ethnic group. Such cultural process transmissions by means of human migration produce archipelagos of diasporic communities, constituted by structures of ethnic practices, extending out from their geographic bases. For example, the migration of Mexican workers from the southern state of Oaxaca, moving through the region of Ciudad Juarez to the region of Chicago, generates an ethnic diasporic cultural network with nodes in the ethnic home region (Oaxaca), one transitional city region (Ciudad Juarez), and a terminal city region (Chicago), connected by transmission processes. Interregional cultural networks of this kind reflect constant transformation as diasporic groups interact with the culture of “host” groups, as new members of the diaspora arrive from the geographic base, and as other means of information transmission enable processes at various nodes in the network to be transformed by the effects of processes at other points (e.g. changes in religious practices in a diasporic node effecting transformations at other diasporic nodes and in the geographic base nodes in the home country).
Political processes introduce other sources of interregional network development. Such processes include the communication of legal or extra-legal norms across space and, importantly, their enforcement through the exercise of authority in myriad local contexts. For example, the passage of statutory law by some state organization, claiming legislative authority over a jurisdiction with fixed boundaries containing multiple city regions, constitutes a given political process whose effects must be transmitted across jurisdictional space. In accordance with the theory heretofore developed, the transmission of the law over space will be effected through the space of cities, with the technological means to undertake the required communication of information across regional spaces. The speed at which information of the law can be received across jurisdictional space varies in relation to differential access to means of communication – other cities will receive the information first and diffuse it across their regions via appropriate means of communication. From here the effects of the political process by which the law was passed will vary based on particular way in which other, local processes shape the enforcement process undertaken differentially across jurisdictional space. In this manner, the interregional political network configured by the transmission of legal norms connects with intra-regional political networks in a continuous, multi-directional interchange of information and effects, shaping the enforcement of the law and the processes through which legal norms are produced at spatio-temporally defined and delimited network nodes.
At this point, it is worth summarizing the arguments that I have, in this section, attempted to convey with regard to globalization. First, it conforms to an imagery of multidirectional interregional network connections emanating from cities, which occupy a central role in the articulation of intra-regional networks integrating their non-urban hinterlands. This conception of globalization is, thus, constructivist in the sense that it is constituted as an aggregation of relatively long networks that are, individually, constructed from the linking of individual, local nodes.[18] It is not a monolithic force existing continuously in an omnipresent “out there,” antagonistically confronting individual, local agents and rendering them passive victims of globally extensive economistic logics. Second, the imagery of globalization largely conforms to Jacobs’ understanding that cities actively constitute, as a matter of definition, interregional city systems. On the other hand, I have sought to broaden the understanding conveyed by Jacobs to include not only networks constituted by commercial exchange processes but also by every other economic, cultural, and political process. Cities, thus, exist as connectors for every kind of process articulated through networks over relatively long distances.
Again, approaching from the opposite direction, every kind of process constituting a network over relatively long distances in Cartesian space requires a city to forge its connections. Globalization, within this framework of networks, simply constitutes a concept for describing the complex range of interregional networks articulated through the space of cities, stretching ever-longer distances by means of transmission technologies that bend Cartesian space, creating the myriad topological spaces of networks.[19] By this definition of globalization, every city is engaged in globalization to the extent that, by definition, every city articulates long distance connections with other cities.
This constitutes the basic conception of globalization that I mean to convey within this project. On the other hand, if I was to leave the discussion of globalization in this section at the idea of long distance interregional network articulations through cities, then I would be exposing this project to the impact of a glaring analytical absence: notably, the fact that cities are, generally, contained by political entities called nation-states. In this regard, I have to specify not only the relationship of the city, as I have defined it so far, to the nation-state, but also the relationship of the nation-state to my conception of globalization.
Nation-states, as they will be understood in this project, are organizations/entities constituted by structures of political processes whose spatio-temporalities can be patterned as networks, defined across a Cartesian space with given jurisdictional boundaries. Such a Cartesian space can be described as relational insofar as the capacity of a nation-state to claim political sovereignty over a space depends on its relationship to the political processes defining other nation-states, contestation of boundaries (e.g. military actions) between nation-states, and other social processes (e.g. commercial exchange, immigration of culturally heterogeneous groups) transcending but penetrating its boundaries. It also depends on myriad economic, cultural, and ecological processes internal to its boundaries, whose effects either strengthen or undermine the capacity of a nation-state to maintain its integrity. In this sense, cultural processes defining a collective history and a common sense of nationhood, linked, in part, to the political process of citizenship, operate over the Cartesian space internal to the nation-state’s political defined boundaries as networks, linked structurally (as mutually constituted/constitutive sets of processes) and spatio-temporally (as overlapping and intersecting networks) to the political processes constituting the nation-state as source of legal authority and a sovereign within its space.
Thus, as a nation-state, France exists as an overlapping set of political networks. Such networks articulate the transmission of effects of state political processes by the central government in Paris to all of the nation’s geographic departments and the effects of diverse enforcement processes from the departments through concentric, hierarchical layers of authority to the central government in a multidirectional framework of determinations. The capacity of the French state to maintain political control over a geographic space like Corsica depends, moreover, on the particular networks, facilitating the transmission of use values, people, and information to undertake both domestic processes of law enforcement and public services, and to undertake military operations to assert the political power of the French state relative to neighboring nation states. In addition, cultural processes, consistent with Althusser’s (1971: 141-148) understanding of ideological state apparatus, occurring in innumerable spaces (e.g. schools, churches, households, cafes, etc…) articulate distinct networks through which information moves with diverse media (e.g. person-to-person conversation, books, television), reinforcing and/or undermining the constitutional legitimacy of the French state and the claim of French central state authority across innumerable geographical spaces within the defined boundaries of the nation-state. Finally, patterns of commerce within local departmental regions and between departments and the Paris city region, shaped, in part, by the political process of the French central state, by those of the European Union, and by those of the World Trade Organization (e.g. concerning the continued existence of agricultural subsidization), articulate particular economic networks that may both reinforce and undermine the internal integrity of France as a nation-state in diverse ways.
An understanding of the nation-state as a particular kind of network space, encompassing articulated political, economic, and cultural networks, puts the nation-state on a footing with my network definition of the city. The interaction of the processes articulating these networks over Cartesian space produces, with varying degrees of territorial integrity, an envelope in Cartesian space, encompassing a defined and variously legitimated or contested political boundary and a continuous range of internal space. If the city exists as an intersection of local/intra-regional networks and long distance/interregional networks, then some of the networks intersecting in the city define it and its region as entities contained within the envelope of a nation-state. For example, the networks constituted by federal political processes, certain cultural processes relating to a shared national history, and economic processes relating to internal/national exchange relationships bind the city region of Boston to the United States as a discrete geographic area contained by the political boundaries of the United States as a nation-state.
Critically, however, the nation-state is only one of myriad possible envelopes, articulated by networks, within which the city and its region may be contained. Numerous contemporary accounts on the city and city regions, like those of the regional economic theory and the control and coordination theory approaches noted in the preceding chapter, reinforce conceptions of globalization as a set of economic processes promoting, at least in part, the disarticulation of cities from national economic space. The notion of a “global commodity chain,” for example, expresses the conception of integrated production, circulation, and exchange networks for use values transcending national boundaries and, at least in part, undermining the capacity of individual nation-states to exercise effective macroeconomic policy with respect to the operation of commodity chains transcending and penetrating their boundaries (Gereffi et al., 1994). In the same respect, Taylor (1994; 2004: 179-193, 196-214) presents an especially radical but compelling account, linked specifically to Jacobs’ rejection of the nation-state as a legitimate, coherent economic entity. Specifically, Jacobs argues, nation-states constitute “grab bags of very different economies” (Jacobs, 1984: 32), combining politically captive but economically dynamic city regions with relatively stagnant city regions and wide, contiguous, but relatively disconnected, non-urban spaces separated from any city region. For Jacobs, “cities are unique in their ability to shape and reshape the economies of other settlements” (Ibid: 32) and, hence, cities, not nation-states, constitute the “basic, salient entities of economic life” (Ibid: 31).
Taylor proceeds to explicitly merge Jacobs’ position on the economic centrality of cities with an historical account, borrowing heavily from World Systems theory, arguing that the history of the modern World System of capitalism has coincided with the sequential productions of a metageography, defined as an “unexamined spatial discourse that provides the framework for thinking about the world across the whole gamut of human activities and interests” (Taylor, 2004: 180). Taylor uses the conception of metageography in order to argue that the intensification of international connections associated with globalization, and, critically, the role of cities in facilitating such connections, poses the opportunity for the transition away from a metageography configured as a mosaic of territorially bounded nation-states and national macroeconomies to one configured on interregional/interurban networks. Notwithstanding the centrality of economic processes to the creation of such a metageography, Taylor elaborates on effects to non-economic processes, introducing, as outcomes of globalization, the potentiality of new interregional networked political sovereignties and the construction of cosmopolitan cultural self-identifications transcending, at least in part, national/ethnic identities linked to the political processes of the nation-state. The conception of globalization advanced by such a metageography paints the image of a post-national world of networked cities in which the nation-state, as an accepted receptacle of political power and coherent macroeconomic organization and the wellspring of cultural self-identification since the time of the Treaty of Westphalia, becomes a structural anachronism, unnecessary to the workings of interregional economic networks and, perhaps, an impediment to development of networked forms of urban or interurban political sovereignty.
It suffices to say that Taylor’s post-national metageography currently manifests itself only as a theoretic argument seeking the moment within which to become an “unexamined spatial discourse” at the level of everyday human existence. That is to say, using language heretofore advanced, Taylor’s metageography performs a reality to whose formation it can, in fact, indirectly contribute. It represents, moreover, the performance of a reality that I mean to take seriously in advancing my own theorization of cities in relation to globalization.
It would be a serious mistake, on my part, to write out the nation-state as a meaningful political agent in processes constituting the city. The possibility for development of interregional economic networks, in particular, requires that no irresolvable obstructions exist to the extension of networks. Such a requirement necessitates the presence of long distance transmission infrastructures, but it also presumes the existence of continuous expanses of Cartesian space for transmission pathways within which political processes will secure/facilitate rather than impede transmissions. One extreme version in which long distance commercial network development achieved facilitation by means of a particular set of state political processes is evident in development of the “Silk Road” through central Asia in connection with the establishment, by military means, of narrow and tenuous political networks by divergent Mongol khanates in the Thirteenth century (Allsen, 1997). In the contemporary context of interregional economic network development, the nation-state, as the dominant form of political organization, generally maintains the capacity to provide the space necessary to develop and stabilize over longer periods such interregional transmission pathways.
Moreover, to the extent that contemporary interregional commercial exchange networks have been characterized by a trend of liberalization, it must be acknowledged that such liberalization has been effected, in part, through political processes by individual nation-states, engaging in bilateral and multilateral deliberation with other nation-states to permit the penetration of their boundaries by particular network forms. The World Trade Organization (WTO), as an organizational entity governing interregional commercial networks, operates through the participation and at the behest of nation-states, which constitute its members. Interregional network development at the present time is predicated, in part, on, rather than precluded by, the existence of nation-states. As a practical matter of analyzing the position of the nation-state within contemporary globalization, this project, thus, concurs more strongly with the position of Hirst and Thompson (1999) in their acknowledgement of the continued political vitality of the nation-state under globalization than with Ohmae’s (1995) enthusiastic pronouncement of the nation-state’s death.
On the other hand, arguing from an analogous position to that of Jacobs and Taylor, it is one thing to concede a critical role to the nation-state in facilitating interregional network development, but it is quite another thing to imply that an interregional network is any more significant if it is, simultaneously, international. The latter modifier describes a relationship between nation-states that I do not intend to emphasize or even utilize again in defining globalization as a set of processes connecting regional spaces focused on cities. In concluding this section, I mean to explain why I think a city-centric/interregional, but not international, conception of globalization is important, quite specifically, to Marxism.
To the extent that Marxism, as a theoretic tradition centered on class processes, contains a commitment to internationalism, witnessed in various incarnations of international working class movements from the 1860s to the present day, it must come to terms theoretically with the nation-state. However class is theorized in Marxist accounts to conceptualize a fundamental commonality that transcends political/jurisdictional boundaries on a global scale to unify all workers/producers of surplus value engaged in capitalist production processes, Marxism must recognize, at least as a condition of struggle for international solidarity against bourgeois nationalism, the existence of traversable national boundaries, continuous state spaces contained by such boundaries, and political and/or cultural processes instituting them. In defending internationalism, Marxian theory, at least implicitly, draws a global geography of nation-states and, in the case of certain theorists (e.g. Luxemburg, 1976), culturally (ideologically, linguistically, etc.) autonomous nationalities contained within the political/jurisdictional boundaries and integrated domestic market space of multi-national states (e.g. autonomous Polish national/cultural space integrated economically and politically into the state space of late Tsarist Russia).[20] Succinctly, Marxist internationalism accepts a link between, on the one hand, the political structure of the nation-state and/or the cultural structure of national/ethnic groupings and, on the other hand, the geographic identification of continuous territorial spaces organically belonging to the nation-state,[21] even as it attempts to forge transnational linkages based on class-identifications.
The problem with this territorialization of the nation-state is that it often co-mingles urban and non-urban spaces without adequately conceiving of the extent to which the nation-state constitutes a complex envelope of heterogeneous spatial forms, unevenly connected to economic, cultural, political, and physical processes transcending the jurisdictional boundaries of the nation-state. Cities and their proximate hinterlands are exposed to the effects of processes transcending nation-state boundaries in qualitatively different ways than relatively disconnected non-urban spaces. These differences both confer on agents in cities a kind of relational power over economic processes not possessed by agents in distant non-urban spaces[22] and exact from cities, as the price of openness, a degree of vulnerability to the effects of cultural processes manifesting a corrosive and subversive impact to cultural processes on which the nation-state relies to cement its hold over Cartesian state space. To a great extent, the role of cities in interregional transmission processes implies that cities must function as gatekeepers for all regions of the nation-state relative to the effects of processes transcending nation-state boundaries.
Cities like New York, London, and Paris accumulate linkages to cultural, political, and economic processes outside of the nation-states within which they are located whose effects will never reach Ohio, Lancashire, or l’Haut Rhône in an unmediated form. Direct investments of capital by foreign capitalist firms to facilitate commodity production and extraction of surplus value in particular city regions transform, however imperceptibly, the degree to which cities integrate multiple national economies. The organization of surplus value for such firms reflects a multinational flow of distributed surplus values, from production/appropriation nodes in particular city regions, to capitalist boards of directors at receiving nodes across national jurisdictional boundaries. In this manner, the conditions of existence for surplus value production in one city region include economic (e.g. procurement of finance) and political (e.g. state monetary, fiscal, and regulatory policy) processes in other nation-states (Ruccio et al., 1991: 34). This integration in the organization of surplus value across national jurisdictional boundaries does not, however, imply the integration of two national economies, but the integration of geographically dispersed sites/nodes of class processes in or through two city-regional economies, contained by different nation-states. Again, flows of money capital from a Chinese capitalist firm in Shanghai invested in commodity production in the New York or Los Angeles regions do not necessarily or immediately integrate rural economies in Oklahoma or Indiana into a single globally extensive economic network connecting them to rural economies in Shanxi or Shandong province.
In addition to flows of capital, extensions of class networks across national jurisdictional boundaries involve flows of labor power, some professional, some unskilled. Migration of labor power into a city region can reshape practices in heterogeneous, skill-specific markets, transforming local labor-management relations (e.g. strengthening or undermining labor organization, raising or lowering skill-specific compensation rates). In this regard, Sassen’s (1990) claim that the development of advanced producer service production processes in certain cities transforms local structures of formal and informal market demand for labor power, on the one hand, enhancing demand for skilled professionals, technicians, and unskilled consumer service workers and, on the other hand, eroding demand for semi-skilled manufacturing workers, constitutes an important argument on the effects of globalization on urban markets for labor power. Assuming the basic validity of Sassen’s hypothesis for purposes of argument, expansion of demand for unskilled migrant labor power in informally structured markets for domestic cleaning and childcare services in Boston does not imply that similar demands for labor power should arise in rural Maine or even in relatively isolated, deindustrialized manufacturing towns in Western Massachusetts like Pittsfield.
Beyond the economics of markets for labor power, human migration imposes relevant cultural effects on cities. Immigrant populations, engaged in cultural processes at variance with those of host nation-states, contribute to a cumulative corrosion/subversion of the geographically defined cultural connection of the city to the nation-state. In some cases, the persistence of such cultural practices or, rather, the appearance of persistent cultural differences between domestic and immigrant populations/failure of assimilation may reflect the presence of survival strategies by immigrant groups in negotiating insoluble racial differences relative to “native” populations. However such differences arise, enhanced migration to cities may yield a kind of cultural disarticulation, or, more properly speaking, the articulation of city spaces into multiple, overlapping heterogeneous transnational cultural networks at least partly liberated from traditional national territorial spaces.
At issue, as economic, political, and cultural networks extend to greater lengths/become more global, is the capacity of nation-state and national cultural processes, attaching specifically urban populations to territorial state space, to assimilate, fully or at least marginally, new, more intense waves of transnational cultural network formation, accompanying the formation of new transnational economic networks through the space of cities. That is to say, the engagement of city economies with global networks in the migration of labor power and the introduction of transnational ethnic/cultural processes forces nation-states to synthesize divergent trajectories in domestic and multiple, heterogeneous transnational cultural processes in order to maintain the cultural-geographical suturing, within the territorial envelope of the nation-state, of cities to non-urban spaces, relatively disconnected from globalization.
The problem that Marxism, and Marxist internationalism in particular, thus, faces is to articulate an understanding of globalization that will perform the partisan reality it seeks to advance, relative to class processes. Namely, Marxism seeks to create spaces within a continuously developing global economy for communism, as the collective appropriation and distribution of surplus labor by its producers. The status of the nation-state in relation to this larger partisan project is theoretically ambiguous by virtue of the complex, overdetermined relationship between state political processes and class processes, a relationship irreducible to last instance determination by the economic. Fundamentally, at stake is the capacity of the nation-state to secure particular political conditions of existence for the development of communist class structures, either by actively privileging communism by means of policy (e.g. explicit state recognition of collective surplus appropriation/distribution, preferential tax policies, etc.) or by supporting a liberal economic developmental environment that does not politically or economically stifle the development of communist structures.
It is a contention of this project, one supported by the perspectives of Jacobs (1984) and Taylor (2004), that cities, not nation-states, exist as a geographically central focus for the constellation of economic, political, cultural, and physical processes involved in globalization, and, in fact, that globalization merely describes connections that cities have, by definition, always made with other city-regional economies. Moreover, I will commit the argument in chapter 3 to the proposition that in such an environment of free and furious economic development, induced, in part, by globalization, radical degrees of class structural heterogeneity are conceivable. On the other hand, the creation and policing of national jurisdictional boundaries, however liberal in nature, and concomitant cultural processes, tying economically disconnected urban and non-urban populations together through a fictive connection to a common land space, hinders, at least in some degree, the development of such vigorous environments. In this sense, concurring at least in part with Hardt and Negri’s (2004) imagery of democratic possibilities in articulation of the global multitude and the destruction of existing forms of national sovereignty, this project asserts the need for Marxian theory to sever its connection to an internationalism predicated on a meta-geography of nation-states and pursue a more rigorous, borderless globalism.[18] Approaching from the perspective of ANT, Law (2004) suggests, in a similar manner, that the global “is specific to each location, and if it is bigger or smaller then it is because it is made bigger or smaller at this site or that” (2004: 24, emphasis in original).
[19] This imagery of globalization conforms, at least in part, with Hardt and Negri’s (2001) conception of the construction of Empire through the production of impersonal network structures in which “there is no place of power – it is everywhere and nowhere” (2001: 190). The emphasis in this project in theorizing interregional networks is, again, clearly different, however. As with Castells’ network society (2000A) and Deleuze and Guattari’s (1987) concept of rhizomatic, fluid networking, Hardt and Negri’s theorization of Empire seeks to dissolve fixed spatialities and emphasize the placeless, non-stationary character of information flows/exercise of power by capitalist firms and undifferentiated state actors– this project seeks to articulate the nodal spatiality of the networks and argue the critical role played by cities in such articulations, especially when the networks are globally extensive.
[20] Neither Luxemburg’s affirmation of cultural autonomy for Polish regions in pre-World War I Russia nor Lenin’s pre-1917 support for complete national self determination for Poland and other Russian ethnic minorities (Lim, 1995) appear to support the contention by Hardt and Negri (2001) that Marxist internationalism, as a matter of organizational practice, was predicated on an anti-nationalist position.
[21] I am indifferent, in this respect, to the question, treated by Balibar (1990), concerning whether nations, as ethnically or otherwise culturally defined groupings, give rise to political states or whether state political processes, under selectively inclusive, liberal politics, give rise to nations, reflecting Anderson’s “imagined communities” (1991). The key point that I mean to emphasize is that the cultural production of a symbolic geography of the nation-state operates as a condition of existence for the nation-state, however it originates.
[22] What I have in mind here is the degree of power over, for example, financial flows, enjoyed by financial sectors firms in the City of London, relative to industrial or retail/wholesale firms in the deindustrializing Northern English counties (Massey, 2007). As Gibson-Graham (2006B: 23-51, 127-163) argue, to the contrary, agents in relatively disconnected, non-urban regions are not powerless in the face of global flows of finance capital, information, other use values, and people. Economic agents in the Latrobe Valley of Australia and the Pioneer Valley of Massachusetts in the U.S. possess a different relational capacity to engage with globally extensive economic processes in alternative ways, but, notwithstanding, I mean to probe the particular aspects of the relational power wielded by cities because I find it particularly relevant, though by no means essential, to the manner in which other regions of nation-states engage with globalization.