Thursday, March 3, 2022

Introducing Marxism and the City in Globalization I


Chapter 1: Introducing Marxism and the City in Globalization


The purpose of this chapter is to evaluate theoretic issues raised by the Marxian tradition.  The issues discussed here relate specifically to the ways in which Marxian theorists have approached the city, but they touch on more general considerations of how Marxian theorists have defined class and the importance assigned by Marxian theory to capitalism as a class structure in multifarious, diverse fields of Marxian theory and analysis. 

Specifically, I intend to situate this project, as a contribution in Marxian theory, relative to other contributions to a Marxian theory of the city.  In this regard, I mean to argue, definitively, that a substantial body of theory already exists in Marxism with regard to the city, and I intend to take these contributions into account in formulating the specific theoretic contribution that forms the core purpose of this project.  Specification of these approaches serves relevant purposes for the work to follow.  In particular, I seek to emphasize the formative significance of works by Lefebvre, Castells, Harvey, and various other theorists concerned with understanding the city as an object of theory in the development of my own approach.  Of equal importance, I want to argue, definitively, how and why the account that will follow in subsequent chapters is different from earlier Marxian theories of the city by specifying, in this context, how the general understanding of Marxian theory advanced in this project differs in significant ways from other theories.  Most succinctly, the survey advanced in this chapter on Marxian theories of the city, as an object of globally expansive capitalism, will emphasize that these approaches have axiomatically labeled the contemporary city as capitalist.  It is this labeling that I mean to contest, not in the spirit of arguing that capitalism, as a class structure associated with a set of definitive processes, does not produce its own particular forms of space, but in order to argue that real cities contain a more profound heterogeneity of class structures and that all of these class structures produce their own, heterogeneous, interspersed, and overlapping geographies.[1] 

            Consequent to these particular goals, I will, first, provide a brief survey of Marxian approaches to the city and, further, argue how these approaches have defined and situated the city within theorizations of capitalist globalization.  I will, then, articulate the foundations for an alternative approach by, first, defining the particular Marxian conception of class to be advanced, and, subsequently, by stating definitively how such a conception of class enables the articulation of a more heterogeneous class landscape in cities and in interregional networks, articulated through cities, through which the multiple, diverse, and not exclusively capitalist processes of globalization operate.

Cities as Objects of Capitalist Globalization in Marxian Theory


The account in this section is intended as a brief summary of approaches introduced within the Marxian tradition since the 1960s that have attempted to define the city or the urban.  It, further, inquires into the ways in which Marxian accounts on the city have been affected by larger scale economic transitions in the geographies of capitalism, alluding to the perceived, theorized, and/or real intensification of international trade and capital mobility.  The summary is by no means exhaustive.  Rather, my intention is to raise some important themes in Marxist urban theory and analysis and recognize how this body of theory has been shaped by the transformation of economic, political, and cultural processes associated with globalization in the period since the 1960s.  Most importantly, I mean to define an overriding commonality in this body of theory concerning the ubiquitous, determinate role assigned to capitalist economic processes.  In this regard, the conclusions developed here provide the groundwork for a critique of Marxist urban theories against which the larger approach of this project seeks to develop an alternative. 

            Generalizing about the larger body of Marxist urban theory, the formative historical period for much urban theorizing was the late 1960s.  Marxian theories of the city prior to this period exist as a patchwork collection, devised in the absence of any general project of theorizing space, like Marx and Engel’s (1975A: 32; 1975B: 488) comments on the separation of town and country, Engels’ (1975: 324-374) account on the spatiality of workers’ communities in Manchester, or, later, Benjamin’s (1986: 165-167) reflections on the “porosity” of Neapolitan economic space, riddled with the remnants of pre-capitalist class structures.[2]  This is not to say, however, that Marxian theory, or Western Marxism in particular, developed an inherent antagonism toward spatial analysis until the 1960s, as implied by Soja (1994: 39-42, 84-88).  The point is, rather, that certain themes, like Marx’s (1991) conceptualization of land rent or theorizations on geographically uneven development (Trotsky, 2002; Mandel, 1987), remained dormant in the repertoire of Marxian theoretic concepts, waiting for an appropriate conjuncture to be revived and raised to a more adequate state of development, especially with respect to urban, metropolitan, and regional/sub-national geographic scales.   

Geographically, the most important national context for the initial efforts of Marxian theory to come to terms with urban spatiality is France.  Urban theorization develops in this particular conjuncture for numerous reasons.  Like many other Western European economies, France displayed a significant pattern of geographically uneven economic development, favoring the metropolitan economy of Paris at the expense of the remaining national economy.  Existing geographic disproportionalities had prompted the development of state-centric policies, favoring the development of peripheral areas and, especially, development of the services capacity of peripheral metropolitan areas (métropoles d’équilibres) (Cohen, 2002).  Such efforts in France and in other Western European economies were, however, waning by the end of the 1960s, as forced economic decentralization began to represent an excessive fiscal burden to central states.  Nonetheless, the question of state-centric regional developmental policies contributed, in part, to an intensification of interest on the part of French geographic and sociological theorists.  In particular, it nurtured an interest on the part of sociologists, particularly those connected with the French Communist Party (PCF) (e.g. Lojkine, 1972; 1976), in the geographic concentration and regional peripheralization of capital accumulation, linking these processes to already existing Marxist theorizations on uneven development.   

Other theorists, on the margins of official, PCF Marxism, approached the problem of space and, especially, urban space for different reasons.  Lefebvre’s work in theorizing urban space, in particular, emanated as a point of transition from a project of theorizing everyday life (quotidienité) under bureaucratic, state-regulated capitalism, advanced with the intention of understanding how everyday life is shaped by the production of space (1968, 1991).  In turn, Lefebvre’s (2003) initial arguments on the urban, advanced in the immediate aftermath of the events of May 1968, provoked diffuse reactions in a still vibrant environment of intellectual conflict characterizing postwar French Marxism.  The most important such reaction, Castells’ Althusserian-inspired The Urban Question (1977), saw as its task the formalization of a rigorous Marxian theory of the city that would not displace class struggle in favor of a new spatial problematic (i.e. Lefebvre’s concept of urban revolution).  Subsequent empirical investigations on the relationship between urban structures and the development of urban social movements by Castells (1978, 1983) pushed his line of inquiry away from Althusserian-influenced structuralism and, at least to some degree, closer to Lefebvre.  Summarily, the development and contestation of diverse theoretic accounts in the late 1960s and 1970s from Lefebvre, Castells, and the range of PCF-associated theorists had carved out a place in French Marxism for urban and more broadly spatial/geographic inquiry.

Outside of the aforementioned vein of French Marxist theories on the city, the other major vein of Marxian theorization on cities emanates in the 1970s from Anglophone geographic theory, a development for which the work of Harvey, from Social Justice and the City (1973) to The Urbanization of Capital (1985), bears a strong influence.  Harvey’s contribution to this body of theory is particularly important because it represents an effort to transform and spatialize Marxian political economy and to articulate an understanding of urban development anchored against Marx’s theory of rent (1973: 176-194; 1989: 90-108) and circuits of capital accumulation (1989B: 61-83; 2006A: 388-398).  On the other hand, Marxian-influenced geographers also appropriated insights from the more globally focused dependency (e.g. Frank, 1966) and World Systems (e.g. Wallerstein, 2004) theories and from French Régulation school accounts on the transformation of capitalist accumulation regimes and modes of regulation (e.g. Aglietta, 2000; Boyer, 2000). 
Under these influences, the larger body of Marxian-influenced geographic theories that develops over the course of the 1980s and early 1990s transcends the urban scale to assemble a multi-scalar approach, recognizing the importance of larger regions (Scott et al, 2008) and interregional networks in commodity production and circulation of capital (Gereffi et al, 1994; Coe et al, 2004).  At stake in these analyses is the rescaling of capitalist geography, conditioned by political processes associated with Neoliberalism, devolving economic dynamism from the national to regional levels.  For my purposes in this project, these geographic theorizations are relevant because they begin to situate the city in relation to higher geographic scales, facilitating theoretic inquiry into the relationship between cities and interregionally-scaled economic processes, characterizing one dimension of globalization.


[1] This approach, to some extent, follows along lines already charted by Arvidson (1995; 1996; 2000), identifying the city as a space of heterogeneous class structures.  To this extent, the introductory stages of my project, advanced in this chapter, invariable repeat certain criticisms developed by this earlier work, especially on the “capitalocentric” (Gibson-Graham, 2006A: 6) nature of Marxist urban theory and analyses.    
[2] Merrifield (2002) provides some context for the development of “porosity” as a concept in Benjamin’s understanding of the relationship between capitalism and urban space.

No comments:

Post a Comment